But the Treasury is to be commended for
stating what Germany’s partners
dare not: “Germany has maintained a large current account surplus throughout
the euro area financial crisis.” This “hampered rebalancing” for other eurozone
countries and created “a deflationary bias for the euro area, as well as for the
world economy”. The International Monetary Fund has expressed similar
worries.
The German finance ministry responded that its current
account surplus was
“no
cause for concern, neither for Germany, nor for the eurozone, or the global
economy”. Indeed, a spokesman stated that the country “contributes significantly
to global growth through exports and the import of components for finished
products”. This reaction is as predictable as it is wrong. The surplus, forecast
by the IMF at $215bn this year (virtually the same as China’s) is indeed a big
issue, above all for the future of the eurozone.
Export surpluses do not reflect merely competitiveness but also an excess of
output over spending. Surplus countries import the demand they do not generate
internally. When global demand is buoyant, this need not be a problem provided
the money borrowed by deficit countries is invested in activities that can
subsequently service the debts they are incurring. Alas, this does not happen
often, partly because the deficit countries are pushed by the supply of cheap
imports from surplus countries towards investing in non-tradeable activities,
which do not support the servicing of international debts. But in current
conditions, when short-term official interest rates are close to zero and demand
is chronically deficient across the globe, the import of demand by the surplus
country is a “beggar-my-neighbour” policy: it exacerbates this global economic
weakness.
It is no surprise, therefore, that in the second quarter of 2013 the
eurozone’s gross domestic product was 3.1 per cent below its pre-crisis peak and
1.1 per cent lower than two years before. Its highly creditworthy core economy
is subtracting demand, not adding to it. Not surprisingly, the eurozone is also
stumbling towards deflation: the latest measure of year-on-year core inflation
was 0.8 per cent. Since demand is so weak, inflation may well fall further. This
not only risks pushing the eurozone into a Japanese deflationary trap but
thwarts the necessary shifts in competitiveness across the eurozone. The
crisis-hit countries are being forced to accept outright deflation. This makes
ultra-high unemployment inescapable. It also raises the real value of debt. (See
charts.)
The policies pursued by the eurozone, under German
direction, were certain to have this outcome, given the demand-destroying impact
of the all-round fiscal austerity. In a recent paper for the European
Commission, Jan In ‘t Veld argues that
contractionary fiscal policy has
imposed cumulative losses of output equal to 18 per cent of annual GDP in
Greece, 9.7 per cent in Spain, 9.1 per cent in France, 8.4 per cent in Ireland
and even 8.1 per cent in Germany, between 2011 and 2013. Inevitably, monetary
policy is going to find it almost impossible to offset this. Before the crisis,
it could work by expanding credit in what turned into the crisis-hit countries –
above all, in Spain. Today, it is working against the background of a weak
banking system, debt overhangs in crisis-hit countries and an aversion to
borrowing in creditor countries.
The most likely way that a more aggressive monetary policy would be effective
is by depreciating the euro’s exchange rate. If, for example, the ECB were to
undertake large-scale quantitative easing, by buying the bonds of the members in
proportion to their shares in the central bank, a falling euro would be the most
likely result. But that would exacerbate the tendency of the eurozone, operating
under German influence, to force its adjustment on the rest of the world.
As the vulnerable countries shrink their external deficits, while the chief
creditor country remains in surplus, the eurozone is generating huge external
surpluses: the shift from deficit towards surplus is forecast by the IMF to be
3.3 per cent of eurozone GDP between 2008 and 2015. Given the shortfall demand
in the eurozone, the shift might need to be even larger, at least if the
vulnerable nations are to have much chance of cutting unemployment. This is a
beggar-my-neighbour policy for the world. The US has every right to complain
about it, just as others had a right to complain about past US regulatory
failures.
It will be impossible, however, for the eurozone to
achieve prosperity on the basis of export-led growth: it is too large to do so.
It has to achieve internal rebalancing, as well. Hitherto, as the
IMF’s October World Economic Outlook shows,
it is mass shedding of labour that has raised competitiveness, and collapsing
domestic demand that has reduced external deficits in the crisis-hit countries.
Thus the adjustment successes have been the other side of the coin of economic
slumps and soaring unemployment. Yet, even so, the IMF does not forecast
significant reductions in net liability positions. Their vulnerability will
endure.
So what, in brief, is happening? The answers are: creeping
onset of deflation; mass joblessness; thwarted internal rebalancing and
over-reliance on external demand. Yet all this is regarded as acceptable,
desirable, even moral – indeed, a success. Why?
The explanation is
myths: the crisis was due to fiscal malfeasance instead of to irresponsible
cross-border credit flows; fiscal policy has no role in managing demand; central
bank purchases of government bonds are a step towards hyperinflation; and
competitiveness determines external surpluses, not the balance between supply
and insufficient demand.
These myths are not harmless – for the eurozone or the world. On the
contrary, they risk either trapping weaker member countries in semi-permanent
depressions or leading, in the end, to an agonising break-up of the currency
union itself. Either way, the European project would come to stand not for
prosperity, but for poverty; not for partnership, but for pain. This, then, is a
tragic story.
0 comments:
Post a Comment